Bank of England addresses CCPs
03 May 2013 London
Image: Shutterstock
The Bank of England has released two papers on CCPs, which explain loss-allocation rules, and how to balance the costs of default resources with the expected losses.
Paper 19, titled: 鈥淐entral counterparties and their financial resources鈥攁 numerical approach鈥, maintains that new regulatory standards have required central counterparties to have robust processes in place to mitigate their counterparty credit risk exposures.
鈥淎t the same time, the standards allow CCPs to tailor their risk management models. This paper considers how CCPs can optimally determine the relative mix of initial margin and default fund contributions in a stylised setting, by balancing the costs of default resources with the expected losses they protect against,鈥 it said.
Where members are of good credit quality and the probability of experiencing losses is low, the loss-mutualising properties of the default fund are favoured over the defaulter-pays properties of initial margin. Significant tail risks in the markets cleared by the CCP further favour the use of the default fund as a cost-effective insurance against potentially large losses.
By contrast, when members are more likely to default or extreme losses are unlikely, the CCP has incentives to maximise the defaulter-pays collateral it takes, and the benefits of the loss-mutualising default fund are reduced, it added.
鈥淥ur numerical results support the recognition that CCPs should have some discretion over how they set the optimal level and composition of their default resources, based on the specific risks of the markets and portfolios that they clear.鈥
The results also show that changes in collateral costs and capital requirements can have a significant impact on a CCP鈥檚 optimal risk management choices.
Paper 20, titled: 鈥淐entral counterparty loss-allocation rules鈥, states that the insolvency of a CCP could be highly disruptive to the financial system if losses fall on participants in an uncertain and disorderly manner. In contrast to most other financial firms, CCPs鈥 obligations to their members, and vice versa, are governed by a central rulebook.
鈥淐CPs have the ability to include in this rulebook rules setting out how losses exceeding the CCP鈥檚 pre-funded default resources are to be allocated between participants. Indeed, some CCPs have already done so. We term such rules 鈥榣oss-allocation rules鈥.鈥
These could have the advantages, relative to the counterfactual of the disorderly insolvency of the CCP, of offering transparency and predictability to participants; providing for a quick and orderly allocation of losses; and potentially allowing the CCP to continue to provide critical services to the market, added the paper.
鈥淭he detailed design of such rules has important implications for financial stability, as well as for the CCP and its stakeholders. Given these considerations, there is ongoing international work on the design of loss-allocation rules.鈥
Paper 19, titled: 鈥淐entral counterparties and their financial resources鈥攁 numerical approach鈥, maintains that new regulatory standards have required central counterparties to have robust processes in place to mitigate their counterparty credit risk exposures.
鈥淎t the same time, the standards allow CCPs to tailor their risk management models. This paper considers how CCPs can optimally determine the relative mix of initial margin and default fund contributions in a stylised setting, by balancing the costs of default resources with the expected losses they protect against,鈥 it said.
Where members are of good credit quality and the probability of experiencing losses is low, the loss-mutualising properties of the default fund are favoured over the defaulter-pays properties of initial margin. Significant tail risks in the markets cleared by the CCP further favour the use of the default fund as a cost-effective insurance against potentially large losses.
By contrast, when members are more likely to default or extreme losses are unlikely, the CCP has incentives to maximise the defaulter-pays collateral it takes, and the benefits of the loss-mutualising default fund are reduced, it added.
鈥淥ur numerical results support the recognition that CCPs should have some discretion over how they set the optimal level and composition of their default resources, based on the specific risks of the markets and portfolios that they clear.鈥
The results also show that changes in collateral costs and capital requirements can have a significant impact on a CCP鈥檚 optimal risk management choices.
Paper 20, titled: 鈥淐entral counterparty loss-allocation rules鈥, states that the insolvency of a CCP could be highly disruptive to the financial system if losses fall on participants in an uncertain and disorderly manner. In contrast to most other financial firms, CCPs鈥 obligations to their members, and vice versa, are governed by a central rulebook.
鈥淐CPs have the ability to include in this rulebook rules setting out how losses exceeding the CCP鈥檚 pre-funded default resources are to be allocated between participants. Indeed, some CCPs have already done so. We term such rules 鈥榣oss-allocation rules鈥.鈥
These could have the advantages, relative to the counterfactual of the disorderly insolvency of the CCP, of offering transparency and predictability to participants; providing for a quick and orderly allocation of losses; and potentially allowing the CCP to continue to provide critical services to the market, added the paper.
鈥淭he detailed design of such rules has important implications for financial stability, as well as for the CCP and its stakeholders. Given these considerations, there is ongoing international work on the design of loss-allocation rules.鈥
NO FEE, NO RISK
100% ON RETURNS If you invest in only one securities finance news source this year, make sure it is your free subscription to Securities 麻豆影视传媒 Times
100% ON RETURNS If you invest in only one securities finance news source this year, make sure it is your free subscription to Securities 麻豆影视传媒 Times